海洋渔业资源管理中ITQ制度交易成本研究
详细信息    本馆镜像全文|  推荐本文 |  |   获取CNKI官网全文
摘要
二十世纪七十年代以来,随着渔业经济的快速发展,我国海洋渔业资源持续衰退。为了保护渔业资源,我国曾采取了捕捞许可制度等一系列管理措施,但由于种种原因,资源衰退趋势一直未能改变。于是在2000年修订的《中华人民共和国渔业法》中提出实行捕捞限额制度。作为捕捞限额制度的一种,个体可转让配额(ITQ)制度自1973年提出来后就被许多国家所采用,一些国家的实践证明该制度确实能够有效防止捕捞努力的过度增长,保护渔业资源。许多经济学家将其认为是最有效的一种捕捞限额制度,但也有学者指出该制度存在比较高的交易成本,会影响其效率的发挥。国际上对ITQ制度交易成本的研究报道还不多,我国对ITQ制度交易成本的研究则几乎处于空白。
     本文从ITQ制度交易成本对其效率的影响、ITQ制度交易成本的分类、我国海洋渔业中ITQ制度交易成本的影响因素、降低我国ITQ制度交易成本的途径等方面对我国海洋渔业资源管理中ITQ制度交易成本进行了研究。
     研究指出,尽管ITQ制度会如新古典学者指出的那样是一种相对于传统管理制度来说更有效率的渔业资源管理制度,但该制度的交易成本会使总可捕量的确定、配额分配、配额交易偏离最优水平,监督成本的存在也会导致其效率的损失,而且渔民越多,监督问题引起的内生交易成本也越大。
     从交易频率、交易中的不确定性、资产专用性等方面考察我国ITQ制度的交易成本时可以看出,ITQ制度比较适合于大的渔区,由于我国海洋渔业中不确定性比较大、资产专用性比较强,因此我国实施ITQ制度的交易成本会比较高。
     从我国渔业、渔区、和渔民的角度探讨该制度交易成本时可以发现,由于捕捞对象许可和捕捞渔具渔法许可、网目尺寸限制和渔获物幼鱼比例检查等制度与ITQ制度的相容性较高,所以有利于该制度的引入。但捕捞渔民多、渔船数量多、渔民文化水平和技能低、渔民转业成本高、海岸线长和海域宽阔导致的作业分散、捕捞业海上交易频繁、兼捕性强等因素会导致ITQ制度交易成本比较高,尤其是配额分配成本和配额分配后制度执行中的监督成本会比较高。而在目前的渔业生产经营体制和渔区的行政管理制度下,渔民的组织化程度比较弱,在此基础上引入ITQ制度的话,会使配额分配成本和制度执行中的监督成本进一步增加。
     对我国这样一个渔民众多而且兼捕性很强的国家来说,完全依靠当局加强监督来实施ITQ制度的话将会带来昂贵的监督成本。在结合我国国情的基础上,通过巴罗博弈模型的拓展和修正可以证明,在我国渔业资源管理的ITQ制度中,渔区人与人之间的信任与监督之间存在替代作用,熟识信用(声誉效应)会产生“社会嵌入”,这将有利于降低ITQ制度的监督成本;通过将Itoh委托—代理模
With the development of fisheries economy, marine fisheries resources have been declining since 1970s' in China. Series of management countermeasures, such as fishing permits, have been adopted to protect marine fisheries resources, but this trend of declining has not been changed. So fishing quota system was put forward in Fishing Law of the People's Republic of China, which was amended on October 31, 2000. As a kind of fishing quota system, individual transferable quota (ITQ) system was suggested in 1973 for the first time, and was immediately adopted by many countries since then. Experiences from some counties proved that it is able to correct the over fishing behaviors and to protect marine fisheries resources. Some Economists applauded for it as the most efficient fishing quota system, but some other economists argued that its high transaction costs could cause losses in its efficiency. Studies concentrated on its transaction costs are scarce both domestically and internationally.This thesis explored the influence of transaction costs of ITQ system on its efficiency, the classification of its transaction costs, factors which affect its transaction costs in Chinese situation, and countermeasures can be adopted to cut down its transaction costs in China.The author proved that although ITQ system is more efficient than the traditional systems which were used to protect marine fisheries resources, its transaction costs can distort the total allowable catch, the distribution of individual transferable quotas, and the transaction of ITQ, this kind of distortion can cause losses in its efficiency, and the endogenous transaction costs which are brought forth by the supervision problem increase with the number of fishermen.If the transaction costs of individual transferable quota system in China are studied from Williamson's viewpoint, one can find that this system can be mostly used in large fisheries area(such as Zhou Shan and Sheng Si), and that because of the large uncertainty and intense investment idiosyncrasy of Chinese fisheries, the transaction costs of this system will be very high.If one analyze the transaction costs of individual transferable quota system in China from the characteristics of Chinese fisheries, fishing communities, and fishermen, he will find that such institutions as fishing objective permits, fishing method permits, limit on net size, and check on the young fish component of catches are compatible with ITQ system, and so can reduce the transaction costs of it, but there are lots of fishermen and fishing boats in China, the cultural qualities, institutional awareness, and technology of fishermen are low, the costs of transferring fishermen to other industries are high, the shore of Chinese oceans is long, the areas of these oceans are broad, the frequency of transaction in ocean is high, multi-catches often occur in fisheries in China, so the transaction costs of ITQ system in China will be very high., especially the costs of quota distribution and supervision costs existing after the distribution. Additionally, under current economic system of fisheries and administrative system of fishing community, fishermen are weakly organized, which will increase the quota distribution costs and supervision costs of ITQ system.As for a country with multi-catch fisheries and so many fishermen, China has to bear high supervision costs if she completely depends on fisheries administrative department to carry out ITQ system. "Social embeddedness" of the trust relationship between familiars and reputation effects, and the substitution between trust and supervision can be proved to exist in fishing communities and fisheries in China by developing and tailoring the Barro's model of game theory in financing field to the reality of Chinese fisheries. Quota cooperative team can also be proved to be helpful to reduce the supervision costs of ITQ system in multi-catch fisheries by extending Itoh's principal-agent model to multi-catch fisheries in China.On the basis of these perspectives stated above, the author pointed out that because such fishing community
引文
[1] 陈新军(主编),《渔业资源与渔场学》[M],北京,海洋出版社,2004:219—269
    [2] 卢现祥,《西方新制度经济学》[M],北京,中国发展出版社,2004:4—5,15—19,21,23—25,36,38,40—42,45,65—72,80,108,153,155,160,199,
    [3] 蒋学模、张晖明:《高级政治经济学——社会主义总论》[M],上海,复旦大学出版,2001:140—141
    [4] 戴星翼,《环境与发展经济学》[M],上海,立信会计出版社,1996:118
    [5] 戴星翼,《走向绿色的发展》[M],上海,复旦大学出版社,1998:67
    [6] 张维迎,《博弈论与信息经济学》[M],上海,上海人民出版社,2000:82—85,218—219,374—379,403—408,428—437,510,514—516
    [7] 谢识予,《经济博弈论》[M],上海,复旦大学出版社,1997:59—63
    [8] 吴万夫、刘大安主编的《渔业技术经济学》[M],北京,中国科学技术出版社,1995:197
    [9] 张帆,《环境与自然资源经济学》[M],上海,上海人民出版社,1998:35—42
    [10] 王志伟,《现代西方经济学流派》[M],北京,北京大学出版计,2002:241
    [11] 李克国等(主编),《环境经济学》[M],北京,中国环境科学出版社,2004:33
    [12] 杨小凯,张永生,《新兴古典经济学与超边际分析》[M],北京,社会科学文献出版社,2003:90—91,91—110
    [13] 张逎英、宋荣民、闻人勇建,《公共关系学》[M],上海,同济大学出版社,2001:130
    [14] 张国良,裘正义,潘玉鹏,《传播学原理》[M],上海,复旦大学出版社,2004,180—200
    [15] 复世福(主编),《中国水产资源开发利用的经济问题》[M],北京,海洋出版社,1987年6月
    [16] 史济奎(主编),《法律基础与渔业法规教程》[M],上海,同济大学出版社,1990:288,294
    [17] 农业部渔业局,《中国渔业统计年鉴》[M],历年。
    [18] 农业部产业政策与法规司,《农业法律法规规章选编 渔业及相关类》[M],北京,中国农业出版社,2003:4—5,6
    [19] 农业部产业政策与法规司,《农业法律法规规章选编 资源保护与环境保护类》[M],北京,中国农业出版社,2003:52—56
    [20] 毕定邦,《渔业经济学》[M],杭州,浙江人民出版社,1990:228—271
    [21] 中华人民共和国农业部渔业局,《我国渔业五十年大事记》[M],北京,中国农业 出版社,1999:117—379
    [22] 夏国新,张培德,《新编实用管理心理学》[M],北京,中央民族大学出版社,1995:126-128
    [23] 张军(主编)《高级微济学》[M],上海,复旦大学出版社,2002:16—21,90—102
    [24] 郑杭生、贾春增、沙莲香,《社会学概论新编》[M],北京,中国人民大学出版社,1987:274
    [1] 康芒斯,《制度经济学》[M],北京,商务印书馆,1997:85—86
    [2] 道格拉斯.C.诺思 (著),陈郁、罗华平等(译),《经济史中的结构与变迁》[M],上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2003:7,225—226,227—229,329
    [3] Y.巴泽尔 (著),费方域、段毅才 (译),《产权的经济分析》[M],上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002:2,4—8
    [4] 加里.D.利贝卡普 (著),陈宇东等 (译),《产权的缔约分析》[M],北京,中国社会科学出版社,2001:1—11,85—107
    [5] 蔓瑟尔.奥尔森 (著),陈郁、郭宇峰等 (译),《集体行动的逻辑》[M],上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2003:1—42
    [6] 埃莉诺.奥斯特罗姆(Elinor Ostrom),《公共事物的治理之道》[M],上海,上海三联书店,2000:11
    [7] 斯韦托扎尔.平乔维奇 (著),蒋琳琦(译),张军 (校),《产权经济学》[M],北京,经济科学出版社,2000:11,29
    [8] 青木昌彦、奥野正宽 (编著),魏加宁等 (译),《经济体制的比较制度分析》[M],北京,中国发展出版社,2005:1,5,240
    [9] H.范里安 (著),费方域等 (译),《微观经济学:现代观点》[M],上海,上海三联书店,上海人民出版社,2004:495
    [10] 斯蒂格利茨 (著),梁小民、黄险峰 (译),《经济学》(第二版)[M],北京,中国人民大学出版社,2000:468
    [11] 因内思.马可—斯达德勒、J.大卫.佩雷斯—卡斯特里罗 (著),管毅平 (译),《信息经济学引论:激励与合约》[M],上海,上海财经大学出版社,2004:10—22
    [12] 青木昌彦 (著),周黎安 (译),《比较制度分析》[M],上海,上海远东出版社,2002:,48,212
    [13] 杨小凯、黄有光,《专业化与经济组织》[M],北京,经济科学出版社,2000:23—102
    [1] 陈昌海:黄海中部深水区底拖网渔业资源及保护的探讨[J],海洋水产研究,1997,4:47—53
    [2] 陈卫忠、李长松、胡芬:东海区海洋渔业资源近况浅析[J],中国水产科学,1997,9:39—43
    [3] 唐建业,捕捞限额制度:法律与制度研究[D],上海,上海水产大学,2004:28—31,93-96
    [4] 黄硕琳,国际渔业发展的动向[J],上海水产大学学报,2000,1:22—26
    [5] 郭文路,国际渔业管理制度与我国渔业管理发展方向研究分析[D],上海,上海水产大学,2001:11—17,20—27,39—42
    [6] 黄硕琳.专属经济区制度对我国海洋渔业的影响[J].上海水产大学学报,1996,5 (3):182-188
    [8] 郭文路,黄硕琳,曹世娟,个体可转让配额制度在渔业管理中的运川分析[J],海洋通报,2002,4:72—79
    [9] 方水美,苏新红,杨圣云,关于制约捕捞限额制度实施若干因素的探讨[J],中国渔业经济,2002,6:37—39
    [10] 唐建业,黄硕琳,总可捕量和个别可转让渔获配额在我国渔业管理中应用的探讨[J],上海水产大学学报,2000,6:125—129
    [11] 郭文路,黄硕琳,总可捕量制度不同实施方式的比较分析[J],海洋湖沼通报,2001,4:61—69
    [12] T.W.舒尔茨,制度与人的经济价值的不断提高[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002:251—265
    [13] V.W.拉坦,诱致性制度变迁理论[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002:327—370
    [14] L.E 戴维斯、D.C.诺斯,制度变迁的理论:概念与原因[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002:266—294
    [15] 林毅夫,关于制度变迁的经济学理论:诱致性变迁与强制性变迁[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002371—440
    [16] A.A 阿尔饮,产权:一个经典注释[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002:166—178
    [17] H.登姆塞茨,关于产权的理论[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002:96—113
    [18] R.H.科斯,社会成本问题[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002,3—58
    [19] 罗伯特.希格斯(Robert Higgs1982),华盛顿州鲑鱼渔场的合法劝诱技术退步[C],道格拉斯.D.诺思、张五常等(著),李.J.阿尔斯通、思拉恩.埃格特森等(编),罗仲伟(译),《制度变革的经验研究》,北京,经济科学出版社,2003:296—338
    [20] D·C·诺斯(1993),经济运行的历史进程[C],罗汉(主译),《诺贝尔获奖者演说文集 经济学奖》,上海,上海人民出版社,1999:1008-1023
    [21] 张五常,关于新制度经济学[C],科斯,哈特,斯蒂格利茨等著,拉斯·沃因,汉斯·韦坎德(编),李风圣主译,《契约经济学》,北京,经济科学出版社,2000,11:61—83
    [22] 费方域,契约人假定和交易成本的决定因素——威廉姆森交易成本经济学述评之一[J],外国经济与管理,1996,5:26—29
    [23] A.A.阿尔钦和H.登姆塞茨,生产、信息费用与经济组织[C],陈昕,《财产权利与制度变迁》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2002:58—95
    [24] 费方域,交易成本理论与委托代理理论之比较——威廉姆森交易成本经济学述评之四[J],外国经济与管理,1996,8:38—41
    [25] 米歇尔·迪特林奇,机会主义、学习与组织演进[C],约翰克劳奈维根(编),朱舟、黄瑞虹(译),《交易成本经济学及其超越》,上海,上海财经大学出版社,2002:294—324
    [26] D·C·诺思,制度、意识形态和经济绩效[C],詹姆斯.A.道、史迪夫.H.汉科、阿兰.A.瓦尔斯特(编著),黄祖辉、蒋文华(主译),《发展经济学的革命》,上海,上海三联书店、上海人民出版社,2000:109—122
    [27] 高健、平瑛,制约我国海洋捕捞渔业人力资源流动因素的探讨[J],中国渔业经济,2002,5:16—17
    [28] 巴特·努特布姆,建立基于学习的交易模型[C],约翰克劳奈维根(编),朱舟、黄瑞虹(译),《交易成本经济学及其超越》,上海,上海财经大学出版社,2002:429—458
    [29] 保罗·R·贝杰,交易成本与学习技术[C],约翰克劳奈维根(编),朱舟、黄瑞虹(译),《交易成本经济学及其超越》,上海,上海财经大学出版社,2002:405—428
    [30] 李松龄,产权制度与交易成本[J],湘潭大学社会科学学报,2002,9:112—117
    [31] 慕永通,我国捕捞限额制度的性质与路径选择[J],中国渔业经济,2004.3:4-6
    [32] 王必达,田淑萍,后发优势:中国西部地区经济发展的动因分析[J],复旦学报(社会科学版),2001,5:91-95
    [33] 翟兵,渔民协会的作用及经验[J],中国渔业经济,2001,1:35
    [34] 韩兴勇,浅论渔民协会的作用及其发展方向[J],中国渔业经济,2001,6:30-30
    [35] 董建辉,传统农村社区社会治理的历史思考[J],中国社会经济史研究,2002,4: 92—97
    [36] 安德鲁·斯通、布赖恩·利维和里卡多·帕雷德斯(1996),公共制度与私人交易:对巴西和智利商业交易德法规与管制环境德的比较分析[C],道格拉斯·C·诺思、张五常等(著),李·J·阿尔斯通、思拉恩·埃格特森等(编),罗仲伟(泽)《制度变革的经验研究》,北京,经济科学出版社,2003:111—149
    [37] Neils G. Noorderhaven,交易成本经济学中的机会主义和信任[C],约翰·克劳奈维根(编),朱舟、黄瑞虹(译),《交易成本经济学及其超越》,上海,上海财经大学出版社,2002:140—172
    [38] 陈凌,信息特征、交易成本及家族式企业[J],经济研究,1998,7:27—33
    [39] 王淘,人际关系模式与经济组织的交易成本[J],经济研究,1994,8:77—81
    [40] 刘世玉,论道德行为对社会交易成本的影响[J],辽宁税务高等专科学校学报,2003,15 (4):11—13
    [41] 秦诗立、岑丞,商会:从交易成本视角的解释[J],上海经济研究,2002,4:52-60
    [42] 林毅夫,劳动者管理型企业中的监督、横向监督与激励[M],收录于张军(主编)《高级微济学》,复旦大学出版社,2002:90—102
    [43] 徐琦,美国的农村社区研究[J],中国农业大学学报(社会科学版)(总48期),2002,3:76—80
    [44] 刁怀宏,农村组织管理制度的内涵及其特征——用马克思主义分析方法给出的解析[J],安徽大学学报(哲学社会科学版),2001,25 (5):41—45
    [45] 陈万灵,农村社区机制:组织制度及其行为框架[J],学术研究,2002,7:24—28
    [46] 徐云池,农村社区组织行为研究[J],中国统计,1997,7:13—15
    [47] 石磊,组织重构:中国农村面临新的选择[J],上海经济研究,2000,6:3—11
    [48] 胡剑锋,祖辉,建立我国农业行业协会的思路与方案研究[J],浙江学刊,2004,1:192—195
    [49] 黎炳盛,村民自治下中国农村公共产品的供给问题[J],开放时代,2001,3:72—81
    [50] 王庆新,减轻农民负担、维护农民利益:从农村社区组织角度进行的研究[J],上海经济研究,2001,5:56—64
    [51] 杨继荣,农村社区功能补位和组织创新[J],理论与改革,2000,4:45—47
    [52] 林学秋:海洋渔业资源能长久开发利用吗?[J],中国渔业经济研究,1999,3:34—36
    [53] 王德芬:完善休渔制度 巩固伏休成果[J],中国渔业经济,2002,2:16—18
    [54] 张军涛,李哲:中国海洋渔业资源的持续有效利用探讨[J],资源·产业,1999,5:32—35
    [55] 金德举:搞好伏季休渔、保护渔业资源[J],齐鲁渔业,1999,16 (4):27—29
    [56] 张德贤、陈中慧、戴桂林、王乃峰:渔业资源配额微分对策研究[J],资源科学,2000,22(2):61—65
    Tom Tietenberg, Environmental and Natural Resource Economics[M],清华大学出版社,2001:60—84,91,229
    [1] Lee G. Anderson, Privatizing Open Access Fisheries: Individual Transferable Quota[C], In Bromley, D. W. (ed.), Handbook of Environmental Economics. Blackwell Publishers, Cambridge, Mass. 1995:453-474.
    [2] Hardin, G.. The tragedy of the commons[J], Science, 1968,162:1243-1248
    [3] Rimjhim M. Aggarwal, Possibilities and Limitations to Cooperation in Small Groups: The Case of Group-Owned Wells in Southern India[J], World Development , 2000,28 (8): 1481-1497
    [4] Bhim Adhikari, Literature review on the economics of common property resources[J], 2001.2, http://www.york.ac.uk/res/celp/webpages/projects/cpr/tanzaniaJpdf/Annexl.pdf
    [5] H. Scott. Gordon, An Economic Approach to the Optimum Utilization of Fishery Resources[J], Journal of Fisheries Research Board of Canada, 1953, 10 (7): 442—457
    [6] H. Scott. Gordon, The economic theory of a common property resource: The fishery[J], J. Polit. Econ. 1954 , 62: 124—142.
    [7] Berkes F., Local level management and the commons problem[J], Marine Policy, 1986, 10: 215-29
    [8] Alan Randall, Market Solutions to Externality Problems: Theory and Practice[J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 1972,54:175-183
    [9] Jon G. Sutinen and Peter Andersen, The economics of fisheries law enforcement, Land Economics, 1985,61(4): 387-397
    [10] Nik Mustapha Raja Abdullah, K.Kuperan, Robert S. Pomeroy, Transaction Costs and Fisheries Co-management[J], 1998 http://www.co-management.org/download/wp15.pdf
    [11] Jesper Raakjar Nielsen, An analytical framework for studying: compliance and legitimacy in fisheries management[J], Marine Policy, 2003,27:425-432
    [12] Parzival Copes, A critical review of individual quota as a device in fisheries managemenr[J], Land Economics, 1986,62(3):278-291
    [13] Bromley, W.D. Testing for common versus private property: comment[J]. J.Environ. Econ. Manag. 1991. 21: 92-96
    [14] Seijo, J.C.; Defeo, O.; Salas, S. Fisheries bioeconomics. Theory, modelling and management[R]. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper. No.368. Rome, FAO. 1998
    [15] Pearse,Peter H., and James E. Wilen, Impact of Canada's Pacific Salmon Fleet Control Program[J], Journal of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada 1979,36:764-89
    [16] Einar Eythorsson, A decade of ITQ-management in Icelandic fisheries: consolidation without consensus[J], Marine Policy, 2000, 24 : 483-492
    [17] Bonnie J. McCay, Carolyn F. Creed, Alan Christopher, et al, Individual transferable quotas(ITQ) in Canadian and US fisheries[J], Ocean and Coastal Management, 1995,28(l-3):85-U5
    [18] Aaron C. Hatcher, Producers' organizations and developed fisheries management in the United Kingdom: collective and individual quota system[J], Marine Policy, 1997,21(6): 519-533
    [19] Lee.G.Anderson, A note on market power in ITQ fisheriesfJ], Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1991, 21:291—296
    [20] Scott C. Matulich, Ron C. Mittelhammer, and Carlos Reberte, Toward a More Complete Model of Individual Transferable Fishing Quotas: Incorporating the Processing Sector[J], Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 1996,31: 112-128
    [21] Rognvaldur Hannesson, A Note on ITQ and Optimal Investment[J], Journal of Environmental Economics and Management . 2000,40: 181 — 188
    [22] Michael C. S. Kingsley, Food for Thought ITQ and the economics of high-grading[J] , Journal of Marine Science, 2002,59: 649
    [23] R. Arnason, Minimum information management in fisheriesfJ], Canadian. J. Economics 1990,23:630-653.
    [24] Ralph E. Townsend, Transferable dynamic stock rights[J], Marine Policy, 1995,19(2): 153-158
    [25] Ralph E. Townsend, Beyond ITQ: property rights as a management tool[J], Fisheries Research 1998, 37: 203-210
    [26] Tsjalle van der Burg, Neo-classical economics, institutional economics and improved fisheries management , Marine Policy , 2000,24: 45-51
    [27] Richard McGarvey. Demand-side fishery management: integrating two forms of input control[J], Marine Policy, 2003, 27:207 - 218
    [28] Einar Eythorsson,Theory and practice of ITQ in IceIand[J], Marine Policy, 1996,20,(3): 269-281
    [29] Asgeir Danielsson, Fisheries Management in Iceland[J], Ocean & Coastal Management, 1996, 35(2-3): 121-135
    [30] C.J. Batstone, B.M.H. Sharp, New Zealand' s quota management system: the first ten years[J], Marine Policy, 1999, 23 (2): 177 - 190.
    [31] C.J. Batstone and B.M.H. Sharp, Minimum information management systems and 1TQ fisheries management[J], Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 2003,45: 492 - 504
    [32] Diane P. Dupont, R. Quentin Grafton, James Kirkley, Dale Sqires, Capacity utilization measures and excess capacity in multi-product privatized fisheries[J], Resource and Energy Economics, 2002,24: 193-210
    [33] Gisli Palsson &Agnar Helgason, Figuring fish and measuring men: the individual transferable quota system in the Icelandic cod fishery[J], Ocean & Coastal Management, 1995,28(1-3): 117-146
    [34] David Symes and Kevin Crean, Privatization of commons: the introduction of individual transferable quota in developed countries[J], Geoforum, 1995, 26(2): 175-185
    [35] Unnur Dis Skaptadottir, Women coping with changes in an Icelandic fishing community: a case study, Women's Study International Forum, 2000, 23(3):311-321
    [36] W.P.Davidse, L.V. McEwan, and N. V.estergaard, Property rights in fishing: from stateproperty towardsprivate property?[J], Marine Policy, 1999, 23( 6): 537— 547
    [37] Ragnar Arnason, RoK gnvaldur Hannesson, William E. Schrank, Costs of fisheries management: the cases of Iceland, Norway and Newfoundland, Marine Policy , 200:24: 233-243
    [38] Tracy. Yandle, The challenge of building successful stakeholder organizations: New Zealand's experience in developing a fisheries co-management regime[J], Marine Policy, 2003, (27) : 179-192
    [39] Rogerson,W.P. The First-Order Approach to the Principal — Agent Problem[J], Econometrica, 1985, 53(6):1357-1367
    [40] Kuperan K, Abdullah NMR, Pomeroy R. Measuring transaction costs of fisheries co-management[J]. Marine Resource Economics, 1998; 13(2): 103 - 14
    [41] Dale Squires, Harry Cambell, Stephen Cunningham, Christopher Dewees, R Quentin Grafton, Samuel F Herrick, Jr, James Kirkley, Sean Pascoe, Kjell Salvanes, Bruce Shallard Bruce Turris, and Niels Vestergaard, Individual Transferable Quotas in Multispecies Fisheries[J], Marine Policy, 1998,22 (2): 135-159
    [42] Bjorn Hersoug, Petter Holm, Stein Arne Ranes, The missing T. Path dependency within

© 2004-2018 中国地质图书馆版权所有 京ICP备05064691号 京公网安备11010802017129号

地址:北京市海淀区学院路29号 邮编:100083

电话:办公室:(+86 10)66554848;文献借阅、咨询服务、科技查新:66554700