对外贸易与产业地理
详细信息    本馆镜像全文|  推荐本文 |  |   获取CNKI官网全文
摘要
改革开放以来,随着对外贸易的快速发展,中国日益全面而深入地融入到全球经济中,与此同时,国内的产业地理(“产业”本文限定为制造业)也发生了深刻的变化:大多数产业在东部沿海地区集聚,东部省份聚集了来自全国的劳动力和来自全球的资本。从21世纪第一个十年的中期开始,随着区域开发政策的不断实施,国内外经济一体化程度持续深化,东部地区的劳动密集型产业开始向中西部地区进行梯度转移,国内市场对产业空间分布的影响作用相对增强,但沿海地区贸易出口的优势依然支撑着产业在东部地区的份额领先。
     毫无疑问,中国产业地理的变迁既与国内的市场化改革有关,更与以对外贸易为特征的全球化密不可分。NAFTA使墨西哥城的制造业分散于墨西哥的美墨边界地区,欧盟一体化加剧了意大利的南北发展差距,对外开放让大量制造业企业在中国的东部沿海地区集聚——贸易自由化是塑造产业地理的重要力量。贸易开放带来的是市场规模的扩大,而市场规模正是新经济地理理论解释产业空间分布分布的基础变量:较大的市场会使得具有规模经济的企业生产成本更低,这鼓励了企业规模的扩张并吸引新的企业进驻此地;另一方面,市场规模大的原因在于许多企业和消费者也聚集在那里,市场获得、运输成本和要素流动形成了互为因果的累积循环。对外贸易的开放,对于面积较大的国家(如中国)而言,不同地区因此获得的市场规模的扩大并不一致,东部沿海地区因在地理结构上靠近国外市场而获得了先天的优势,国家政策的优惠进一步强化了这种优势,沿海地区面临的大的市场吸引企业和工人,而企业对中间投入产品的需求和工人对终端产品的需求使得市场规模更大,从而使得产业持续在东部集聚。但随着国内市场一体化的深入,国内市场的作用开始扩大,产业和企业发生转移和扩散,中国的产业地理开始新的演化。本文运用传统贸易理论、新贸易理论和新经济地理理论结合中国的发展特征,从理论和实证两个方面分析了对外贸易在中国产业地理形成中的影响。与以往研究相比,本文在改进的理论模型、产业地理描述、出口贸易空间特征和以及影响产业地理的因素考察等方面,进行了优化和创新。
     在对现有文献进行归纳、整理和评述的基础上,本文首先拓展了一个分析对外贸易与国内产业地理的模型——一个包含两国三地区的一般均衡模型,模型通过对运输成本和国内两地区非对称等假定的改进处理,能够更准确地描述和解释目前对外贸易开放对中国产业地理的影响。论文接下来利用改进版本的引力模型测度和分析了中国对外贸易成本的变化,通过产业分类和地区分类详尽地描述和刻画了中国产业地理的时空演变,并在此基础上研究中国贸易出口的空间特征。文章的第三大部分是在上述已有研究结果的基础上,再结合新贸易理论、新经济地理理论的理论解释构建计量方程,利用不同指标和数据验证中国对外贸易与产业地理的关系,并以城市经济为研究对象,考察内外部市场获得对地区发展的影响。论文的最后是总结性的结论、政策含义和研究展望。通过理论和实证分析,本文得到了如下主要结论。
     (1)两国三地区模型中,国内两地区不对称的情形下,对外贸易的开放使得具有地理优势的贸易便利地区获得了先发优势,这使得这些地区成为产业的集聚地,要素和产出在此集聚,而且这种优势是不可逆转的。对外贸易成本的降低凸显外部市场的作用,会减缓产业由贸易便利区向国内其他地区扩散的趋势,外部需求的恶化会加剧这种转移的趋势。
     (2)改革开放以来,中国对外双边贸易成本均出现了大幅度的下降。空间上,中国与欧盟、美国的空间距离和运输成本大于中国与中国香港、中国台湾、东盟、韩国和日本的空间距离和运输成本,而双边贸易成本也是前者大于后者。时间上,加入WTO对中国对外双边贸易成本的下降作用明显。对象上,目前中国与东亚新兴地区的双边贸易成本要低于与美日欧等发达国家,开放以来的下降幅度也更大。
     (3)以对外贸易自由化和吸引外资便利化为特征的经济全球化深刻影响着中国的产业地理,不同类型产业的地理分布特征和时空演变趋势存在较大差异。劳动密集型的出口产业迅速发展,依托出口加工贸易,外向度高的产业在东部地区加速集中。2005年前后,制造业特别是高外向度或高劳动密集度产业向中西部地区扩散和转移的趋势开始形成。
     (4)出口集聚促进产出集聚、贸易出口存在空间相关性是中国进行贸易出口的地区存在两个明显的空间特征。这使得贸易出口相比产出具有“更集聚”、“更沿海”、“更东南”的地理特征;出口贸易作为一种有较强示范效应和溢出效应的经济活动,在相互临近的地理区位上存在相关性,这在江苏县域单位的维度上得到了很好的证明。
     (5)中国制造业产业的贸易出口行为能显著地促进其地理集中度的提高,在贸易开放条件下,劳动密集型产业更加明显地表现出集聚的趋势;具有高税收产业的空间分布更为分散;各省区的出口贸易推动了其总体制造业在本地区的聚集;中国总体对外贸易成本的降低也有利于国内各地区制造业总体集聚率的提高;较高的地区经济发展水平、更发达的交通基础设施和处于沿海的地理优势都会显著地提高这些地区的制造业平均集聚率。
     (6)国内外市场获得(潜力)是我国城市经济发展差距的重要原因,在区域中心城市层面显得尤为突出,东部地区的城市具有靠近外部市场的地理特征,国外的市场获得的条件优于其他地区的城市,同时,东部地区城市群密集且经济规模较大,国内市场获得的优势更加明显,这导致了东中西部城市特别是区域中心城市的发展差距。而中西部中心城市发展滞后致使其辐射带动能力弱,这是中国区域发展失衡的重要原因。
After the domestic reform and opening to the world, China has gradually made integration into the global economy comprehensively along with the rapid development of foreign trade. At the same time, profound changes have taken place in the domestic industrial geography ("industry" in this paper is limited to manufacturing):Most of the industry is gathering in the eastern coastal areas, the eastern provinces attract labor across the China and capital from around the world. From the mid-term in first decade of the 21st century, with the continued implementation of regional development policies, domestic and international economic integration continued to deepen, the labor-intensive industries in the eastern region began to gradually shift to the central and western regions, the domestic market's influence for industrial spatial conformation increase relatively. But the advantage of coastal trade is still supporting the more export industry's share in the eastern region.
     There is no doubt that the changes in the domestic industrial geography are relevant to the domestic market-oriented reforms, but also to foreign trade and globalization. NAFTA allows Mexico's manufacturing dispersed in the US-Mexican border region of Mexico. EU integration intensified the development gap between north and south of Italy. Openness to the outside makes so many manufacturing clustered in the eastern coastal areas of China. Trade liberalization is an important force shaping the industrial geography. Trade liberalization enlarges the market scale. market scale is basic variable that the new economic geography theory explain the distribution of spatial distribution of industry:the larger market will allow companies with economies of scale production costs lower, which encourages the expansion of firm's scale and attracts new companies stationed here; the other hand, the larger market is the result of the large number of businesses and consumers gathered there, market access, transport costs and factor mobility form the cumulative cycle. For larger countries (like China), different regions get different added market from the foreign trade and opening. Due to geographical proximity to foreign markets, eastern coastal areas have inherent advantages. Preferential state policies further strengthened this advantage. Facing the largest market, coastal areas is attracting businesses, and business's demand for intermediate input and workers' demand for the end product makes the market larger, so that the industry continued to gather in the east. But with the deepening of the domestic market integration, the role of the domestic market began to expand, industries and enterprises start to shift or spread. China's industrial geography makes a new evolution. We make analysis of foreign trade on the impact of China's industrial geography from both theoretical and empirical perspective. Compared with previous studies, improved the theoretical model, industrial geographical description of spatial characteristics, export trade, and geographical factors affecting industrial inspection, etc., are optimized and innovation in this paper.
     Based on the existing literature summarized, organized, and reviewed, We first develop a model to analyze the relations between the foreign trade and domestic industrial geography-a general equilibrium model that contains two countries three regions. This model can more accurately describe and explain the influence of the opening in foreign trade on China's industrial geography through improvement of domestic transport costs and the asymmetry assumed in two regions. Next we using the improved gravity model to measure and analyze the cost of China's foreign trade. Using the detailed classification of industries and regions, we describe and characterize the temporal evolution of China's industrial geography, and on the basis of results we analyze the spatial characteristics of Chinese exports. The third part is the basis of existing research results combined with new trade theory, the theory of new economic geography theory to construct econometric equations, and using different indicators to verify the relationship between China's industrial geography and foreign trade. Also using urban economy as a case we study the impacts of internal and external markets on regional development. Last is a summary of conclusions, policy implications and research prospects. Through theoretical and empirical analysis, the paper obtained the following main conclusions.
     (1) In the situation of two domestic asymmetric regions in the model of two countries and three regions, the opening of trade makes a geographical area with trade facilitation advantages gained first-mover advantage, making these areas become the place of industry agglomeration, and output elements is in this cluster, moreover this advantage is irreversible. Reduction in trade costs shows the role of external markets, which slowed the industry from trade facilitation area spread to other regions. Deterioration in external demand will intensify the trend of this shift.
     (2)Since the reform and opening, the bilateral trade cost of China has been a significant decline. On the spatial dimension, the distance and transportation costs in China and the European Union, the United States is more than China and Hong Kong, China Taiwan, ASEAN, South Korea and Japan, and the former is more than the latter in bilateral trade cost. On the time dimension, the effect WTO accession on China's foreign trade cost reduction is obvious. On national dimension, China's bilateral trade with the East Asian newly industrialized countries is less than other developed countries like the United States and Japan, and degree of decline is greater after the openness.
     (3)Economic globalization which is characterized by foreign trade liberalization and FDI facilitation impacts profoundly on China's industrial geography. The geographical distribution, temporal and spatial evolution of different types of industry is quite different. Labor-intensive export industries have more rapid development. Relying on export processing trade, export-oriented industries are with high concentration in the eastern areas. After 2004-2005, export-oriented manufacturing, especially high or high degree of labor-intensive industry, begins to spread to the central and western regions.
     (4)Export agglomeration promotes the production agglomeration. There is spatial correlation in exports. This is the two spatial features about the export. Compared to the production, export has the following geographic features:more concentration, more coastal and more southeast. As an economic activity with strong demonstration effect and spillover effects, exports are approaching each other on the geographical location. This county unit in Jiangsu dimension has been well proven the fact.
     (5)The export of China's manufacturing industries promotes the geographical concentration of these industries. On the condition of trade openness, labor-intensive industries are more apparent in the trend of concentration. The industries with high taxes are more dispersed distribution industries. The export trade in provinces will promote its overall industry agglomeration in these regions. Reduction of the cost of China's foreign trade is conducive to the overall agglomeration of manufacturing industries of the regions. Areas with high level of economic development, more developed transport infrastructure and geographical advantages in the coastal city significantly increased the average concentration of manufacturing in these areas.
     (6)Domestic market access is an important reason for the gap of economic development in China's regional urban. This is particularly prominent in urban centers. Due to the advantages of the eastern coast to foreign countries, foreign market access enhanced the gap:the advantages of the eastern region of trade advantages in foreign markets increased China's central and western cities in economic development, the lag of the central and western central cities'development cause its weak radiating capacity, this is the important reason for the imbalance in regional development.
引文
[1]曾庆泳、陈忠暖,基于GIS空间分析法的广东省经济发展区域差异,经济地理,2007(4)。
    [2]范剑勇,市场一体化、地区专业化与产业集聚趋势——兼谈对地区差距的影响,中国社会科学,2004(6)。
    [3]范剑勇,《产业集聚与中国地区差距研究》,上海:格致出版社、上海三联出版社、上海人民版社,2008。
    [4]范剑勇、高人元、张雁,空间效率与区域协调发展战略选择,世界经济,2010(2)。
    [5]范剑勇、王立军、沈林洁,产业集聚与农村劳动力的跨区域流动,管理世界,2006(4)。
    [6]范剑勇、张雁,经济地理与地区间工资差异,经济研究,2009(8)。
    [7]何江、张馨之,中国区域经济增长及其收敛性:空间面板数据分析,南方经济,2006(5)。
    [8]黄玖立,对外贸易、地理优势与中国的地区差异,北京:中国经济出版社,2009。
    [9]黄玖立、李坤望,出口开放、地区市场规模和经济增长,经济研究,2006(6)。
    [10]金煜、陈钊、陆铭,中国的地区工业集聚、经济地理与经济政策,经济研究,2006(4)。
    [11]李坤望、黄玖立,中国贸易开放度的经验分析:以制造业为例,世界经济,2006(8)。
    [12]李坤望、黄玖立、施炳展,中国与主要贸易伙伴的双边贸易自由度——基于新经济地理学的一个衡量,世界经济文汇,2006(4)。
    [13]梁琦,《产业集聚论》,北京:商务印书馆,2004。
    [14]梁琦,《分工、集聚与增长》,北京:商务印书馆,2009。
    [15]梁琦,空间经济学:过去、现在与未来,经济学(季刊),2005(4)。
    [16]梁琦,中国制造业分工及其国际比较,世界经济,2003(12)。
    [17]梁琦、钱学锋,外部性与产业集聚——一个文献综述,世界经济,2007(2)。
    [18]梁琦、吴俊,财政转移与产业集聚,经济学(季刊),2008(4)。
    [19]梁琦,关于空间经济研究的若干认识,广东社会科学,2010(4)。
    [20]藤田昌久、克鲁格曼、维纳布尔斯,《空间经济学》,梁琦主译,北京:中国人民大学出版社,2005。
    [21]林光平、龙志和、吴梅,我国地区经济收敛的空间计量实证分析:1978-2002年,经济学(季刊),2005(4)。
    [22]林毅夫、刘培林,经济发展战略对劳均资本积累和技术进步的影响——基于中国经验的实证研究,北京大学中国经济研究中心讨论稿2003年。
    [23]刘夏明、魏英琪、李国平,收敛还是发散——中国区域经济发展争论的文献综述,经济研究,2004(7)。
    [24]刘修岩、贺小海、殷醒民,市场潜能与地区工资差距:基于中国地级面板数据的实证研究,管理世界,2007(9)。
    [25]刘修岩、殷醒民,空间外部性与地区工资差异:基于动态面板数据的实证研究,经济学(季刊),2008(10)。
    [26]鲁凤、徐建华,中国区域经济差异的空间统计分析,华东师范大学(自然科学版),2007(2)。
    [27]陆铭、陈钊,分割市场的经济增长——为什么经济开放可能加剧地方保护?经济研究,2009(3)。
    [28]骆永民,中国科教支出与经济增长的空间面板数据分析,河北经贸大学学报,2008(1)。
    [29]马栓友、于红霞,转移支付与地区经济收敛,经济研究,2003(3)。
    [30]孟斌、王劲峰,基于空间分析法的中国区域差异研究,地理科学,2005(4)。
    [31]钱学锋、梁琦,测度中国与G-7的双边贸易成本——一个改进引力模型方法的应用,数量经济技术经济研究,2008(2)。
    [32]石敏俊、赵曌、金凤君,中国地级行政区域市场潜力评价,地理学报,2007(10)。
    [33]世界银行,《2009年世界发展报告:重塑世界经济地理》,北京:清华大学出版社,2009。
    [34]孙哲、刘建华,产业地理与结盟游说,世界经济与政治,2007(6)。
    [35]弗里德曼,《世界是平的:21世纪简史》,何帆等译,湖南科学技术出版社,2007。
    [36]许德友、梁琦,中国对外双边贸易成本的测度与分析:1981-2007年,数量经济技术经济研究,2010(1)。
    [37]许德友、梁琦,中国对外贸易成本:测度方法及决定因素---一个基于面板数据的衡量,世界经济文汇,2010(6)。
    [38]许德友、梁琦,金融危机、技术壁垒与出口国企业技术创新,世界经济研究,2010(9)。
    [39]许德友、梁琦,经济一体化、产业集聚与地区差距:一个基于NEG框架的理论综述,中国区域经济,2010(2)。
    [40]许德友、梁琦,珠三角产业转移的“推拉力”分析——兼论金融危机对广东“双转移”的影响,中央财经大学学报,2011(1)。
    [41]许德友,梁琦,县域贸易出口的空间相关性分析,财经研究,2011(5)。将要发表。
    [42]许德友,梁琦,对外贸易与国内产业地理:来自新经济地理学的研究综述,南方经济,2011(7)。将要发表。
    [43]魏浩,中国30个省市对外贸易的集聚效应和辐射效应研究,世界经济,2010(4)。
    [44]吴玉鸣,空间计量经济模型在省域研发与创新中的应用研究,数量经济技术经济研究,2006(5)。
    [45]吴玉鸣、陈志建,居民消费水平的空间相关性与地区收敛分析,世界经济文汇,2009(5)。
    [46]吴玉鸣、徐建华,中国区域经济增长集聚的空间统计分析,地理科学,2004(6)。
    [47]张嘉为、陈曦、汪寿阳,新的空间权重矩阵及其在中国省域对外贸易中的应用,系统工程理论与实践,2009(11)。
    [48]赵伟、张萃,FDI与中国制造业区域集聚:基于20个行业的实证分析,经济研究,2007(11)。
    [49]赵伟、张萃,市场一体化与中国制造业区域集聚变化趋势研究,数量经济与技术经济研 究,2009(2)。
    [50]赵永亮、才国伟,市场潜力的边界效应与内外部市场一体化,经济研究,2009(7)。
    [51]赵永亮、刘德学,市场(潜力)获得与边界效应——区际一体化程度的实证,世界经济文汇,2009(2)。
    [52]赵曌、石敏俊,东北地区市场潜力分析与区域经济发展,地理研究,2009(1)。
    [53]Ades, A.F and E.L Glaeser, (1997), "Trade and circuses:explaining urban giants", Quarterly Journal of Economics, CX(1),195-227.
    [54]Amiti, M.,(1999), "Specialization Patterns in Europe", CEPR Discussion Paper 363, London School of Economics,1997. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, (135):573-593.
    [55]Andersen, J., and Wincoop,Van., (2003), "Gravity with Gravitas:A Solution to the Border Puzzle." American Economic Review,93,170-192.
    [56]Andersen, J., and Wincoop, Van., (2004), "Trade Costs", Journal of Economic Literature,3, 691-751.
    [57]Andersen, J., and Wincoop, Van., (2002), "Borders, Trade and Welfare", Brookings Trade Forum 2001, Susan Collins and Dani Rodrik, eds., Washington:The Brookings Institution, 207-244.
    [58]Anderson, J., (1979), "A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation" American Economic Review.69,106-116.
    [59]Anselin, L. "Spatial Econometrics:Methods and Models", Kluwer Academic,1988.
    [60]Aroca, P., William F., (2005), "Spatial Dimensions of Trade Liberalization and Econmomic Convergence:Mexico 1985-2002." The World Bank Economic Review,19(3),345-378.
    [61]Bai C, Du Y, Tao Z. and Tong S., (2004), "Local protectionism and regional specialization: evidence from China's industries", Journal of International Economics, (63):397-417.
    [62]Baldwin, R., Forslid, R., Martin, P., Ottaviano, G., Robert-Nicoud, (2003), Economic Geography and Public Policy, Princeton:Princeton University Press.
    [63]Behrens, K., Lamorgese, A.R., Ottaviano, G.I.P.and Tabuchi, T., (2007), "Changes in Transport and Non-transport Costs:Local vs Global Impacts in a Spatial Network." Bank of Italy Working Paper, No.628.
    [64]Brackman, S., H. Garretsen, and M. Schramm, (2004), "The Spatial Distribution of Wages: Estimating the Helpman-Hanson Model for Germany", Journal of Regional Science,44(3), 437-466.
    [65]Brulhart, M., (2001), "Evolving geographical concentration of European manufactuang industries", Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, (137):215-243.
    [66]Brulhart, M., (1998), "Economic geography and industry location", World Economy, 775-801.
    [67]Cabrer-Borras, B., and Serrano-Domingo, G., (2007), "Innovation and R&D Spillover Effect in Spanish Regions:A Spatial Approach." Research,36,1357-1371.
    [68]Cairncross, F., (2001), "The Death of Distance:How the Communications Revolution will Change our Lives." London:Texere.
    [69]Chakrabarti, Avik., (2003), "A Theory of the Spatial Distribution of Foreign Direct Investment." International Review of Economics and Finance,12,pp.149-169.
    [70]Chen, Z., Yu, J., and Ming L., (2005), "Economic Opening and Industrial Agglomeration in China", CCER, FED Working Paper No.20050061.
    [71]Ciccone, A., and Hall, R., (1996), "Productivity and the Density of Economic Activity", American Economic Review,86(1),54-70.
    [72]Coughlin and Segev., (2000), "Foreign direct investment in China:A spatial econometric study", World Economy, (23):1-23.
    [73]Crozet M., and P. Koenig, (2005), "The Cohesion VS Growth Tradeoff:Evidence from EU Regions(1980-2000)", ERSA Conference Paper, No. ersa05p716.
    [74]Crozet, M., and P. K., (2004), Soubeyran,"EU Enlargement and the Internal Geography of Countries",Journal of Comparative Economics,32(2),265-279.
    [75]De Bruyne, K., (2003), "The Location of Economic Activity:Is There a Spatial Employment Structure in Belgium?" mimeo, KU Leuven, Leuven.
    [76]Demurger, S, (2001),"Infrastructure Development and Economic Growth:An Explanation for Regional Disparities in China?" Journal of Comparative Economics,29 (1),95-117.
    [77]Demurger, S., Sachs, J., Bao SM., (2002), "Geography, Economic Policy, and Regional Development in China", NBER Working Paper,No.8897.
    [78]Elizond.R.L. and Krugman,P., (1992), "Trade Policy and the Third World Metropolis", NBER Working Paper No.4238.
    [79]Ellison, G. and E. Glaeser, (1999), "The Geographic Concentration of Industry:Does Natural Advantage Explain Agglomeration?" American Economic Review,89(2),311-316.
    [80]James, E., (1964), American Geography: Inventory & Prospect. Syracuse, Syracuse University Press.
    [81]Fan, C. and Scott, A., (2003), "Industrial Agglomeration and Development:A Survey of Spatial Economic Issues in East Asia and a Statistical Analysis of Chinese Regions" Economic Geography,79:295-319.
    [82]Feenstra and Rose, (2000), "Put Things in Order:Trade Dynamics and Product Cycles.", The Review of Economics and Statistics,3,369-382.
    [83]Fujita M., P. Krugman, and A. Venables, (1999), The Spatial Economy:Cities, Regions and International Trade. Cambridge, Mass:MIT Press.
    [84]Fujita M., and D., Hu, (2001), "Regional Disparity in China 1985-1994:the Effect of Globalization and Economic Liberation", Annals of Regional Science 35:3-37.
    [85]Fujita, M., and P. Krugman, (1995), "When is the Economy Monocentric? Von Thunen and Chamberlin Unified", Regional Science and Urban Economics,25(4),505-528.
    [86]Gao, T., (2004), "Regional industrial growth:evidence from Chinese industries", Regional Science and Urban Economics,101-124.
    [87]Ge Y., (2004), "Regional Inequality, Industry Agglomeration and Foreign Trade, The Case of China". UIBE. Mimeo.http://www.uibe.edu.cn/upload/upjmxy/xscg/ywgzlw/22.pdf.
    [88]Haaparanta, P., (1998), "Regional Concentration, Trade, and Welfare", Regional Science and Urban Economics, (28),445-463.
    [89]Hanson G. (1998), "North American economic integration and industry location", Oxford Review of Economic Policy, (14):30-44.
    [90]Hanson, G., (1996), "Localization economies, vertical organization, and trade", American Economic Review, S6:1266-78.
    [91]Hanson, G., (1998), "Market Potential, Increasing Returns, and Geographic Concentration", NBER Working Paper, No.6429.
    [92]Hanson, G., and X., Chong, (2004), "The Home Market Effect and Bilateral Trade Patterns". American Economic Review,94,1108-1129.
    [93]Harrington, J. W., Barnes, T. J., Glasmeier, A.K., Hanink, D. M., Rigby, D. L., (2002), Economic Geography:Reconceiving "the economic". Oxford:Oxford University Press.
    [94]Harris, C., (1954), The geography of manufacturing. In James, P. E. and Jones, C.
    [95]Harris, C., (1954), "The Market as a Factor in the Localization of Industry in the United States", Annals of the Association of American Geographers,44(4),315-348.
    [96]Head, K., and T. Mayer, (2006), "Regional Wage and Employment Responses to Market Potential in the EU", Regional of Science and Urban Economics,36(5),573-594.
    [97]Henderson, J.V (1999), "The effects of urban concentration on economic growth", processed, Brown University.
    [98]Henderson, J.V., T. Lee, and Y-J Lee, (1998), "Externalities, location and industrial deconcentration in a Tiger Economy", processed, Brown University.
    [99]Hu, Dapeng, (2002), "Trade, rural-urban migration, and regional income disparity in developing countries:a spatial general equilibrium model inspired by the case of China, " Regional Science and Urban Economics,32:311-338.
    [100]Isard, W., (1956), Location and Space Economy. New York:John Wiley.
    [101]Jacks, D.S., Meissner, C.M.and Novy, D., (2006), "Trade Costs in the First Wave of Globalization." NBER Working Paper No.12602.
    [102]Kiso, T., (2005), "Does New Economic Geography Explain the Spatial Distribution of Wages in Japan?" Working Paper, University of Tokyo.
    [103]Krugman, P. and Venables, A. (1995), "Globalization and the Inequality of Nations." Quarterly Journal of Economics, November, MIT Press,110(4),857-880.
    [104]Krugman, P. (1991), Geography and Trade. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
    [105]Krugman, P. and R. E. Livas, (1996),'Trade policy and the third world metropolis', Journal of Development Economics,49(1) 137-150.
    [106]Krugman, P., (1991), "Increasing Returns and Economic Geography", Journal of Political Economy,99(3),483-499.
    [107]Le Gallo, Julie and Ertur, Cem., (2005), "Exploratory Spatial Data Analysis of the Distribution of Regional per Capital GDP in Europe,1980-1995." Regional Science,14 Jan, 175-201.
    [108]Lesage, (1999), "A spatial econometric examination of China, economic growth".Geographic Information Sciences, (5):143-153.
    [109]Marshall, A., (1890), Principles of Economics,8th Edition, New York:Macmillan,1948.
    [110]Mion, G., (2004), "Spatial Externalities and Empirical Analysis:The Case of Italy", Journal of Urban Economics,56(1),97-18.
    [111]Niebuhr, A., (2006), "Market Access and Regional Disparities:New Economic Geography in Europe", Annals of Regional Science,40(2),313-334.
    [112]Novy, D., (2008), "Gravity Redux:Measuring International Trade Costs with Panel Data." Working paper, Mimeo, University of Warwick.
    [113]Novy, D., (2006), "Is the Iceberg Melting Less Quickly:International Trade Costs after World War II." Working paper, Mimeo, University of Warwick.
    [114]Novy, D., (2007), "Trade Costs and the Open Macroeconomy." Working paper, Mimeo, University of Warwick.
    [115]Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K., (2000), "The Six Major Puzzles in International Macroeconomics:Is There a Common Cause?" in Ben S. Bernanke and Kenneth Rogoff, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Cambridge:MIT Press.
    [116]Ohlin B., (1957), Interregional and International Trade.Cambridge:Harvard University Press.
    [117]Paluzie, E., Pons, J, and Tirado, D., (2001), Regional integration and specialization patterns in Spain. Regional Studies, (35):28-296.
    [118]Puga, D. (1998), "Urbanisation patterns; European vs less developed countries", Journal of Regional Science,38,231-52.
    [119]Puga, D. and A.J. Venables, (1996), "The spread of industry:agglomeration in economic development", Journal of the Japanese and International Economies,10:440-464.
    [120]Redding S., (1999), "Economy Geography and International Inequality", Journal of International Economics,62:53-82.
    [121]Redding, S., and A. Venables, (2004), "Economic Geography and International Inequality", Journal of International Economics,62(1),53-82.
    [122]Redding, S., (2005), "Spatial Income Inequality", Swedish Economic Policy Review,12 (1),29-55.
    [123]Rosen, K.T. and M. Resnick, (1980), "The size distribution of cities; an examination of the Pareto law and primacy", Journal of Urban Economics,8,165-186.
    [124]Samuelson, P., (1954), "The Transfer Problem and Transport Costs II:Analysis of Effects of Trade Impediments." Economic Journal.64, pp.264-289.
    [125]Scitovsky, T., (1954), "Two Concepts of External Economies", Journal of Political Economy,62(2),52-67.
    [126]Sjoberg O., and Sjohoim F., (2004), "Trade liberalization and the geography of production: agglomeration, concentration and dispersal in Indonesia's manufacturing industry", Economic Geography, (80):287-310.
    [127]Stockman, A. and Tesar, L., (1990), "Tastesand Technology in a Two-Country Model of the Business Cycle:Explaining International Comovements." NBER Working paper, No.3566.
    [128]Surico P., (2004), "Geographic Concentration and Increasing Returns", Journal of Economic Survey, (17):693-708.
    [129]United Nations, (1991), World Urbanization Prospects 1990, New York, United Nations.
    [130]Venables, A.J., (1999), "Regional Integration Agreements:a force for convergence or divergence", World Bank Policy Research Paper.
    [131]Walker, R., (2003), The geography of production. In Sheppard, E. and Barnes, T. J. (eds.), A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford:Blackwell.
    [132]Watts, H. D., (1987), Industrial Geography. London:Longman Scientific & Technical.
    [133]Wen M., (2004), "Relocation and agglomeration of Chinese industry", Journal of Development Economics, (73):329-347.
    [134]Wheaton, W. and H. Shishido, (1981), "Urban concentration, agglomeration economies and the level of economic development", Economic Development and Cultural Change,30, 17-30.
    [135]Williamson, J. (1965), "Regional inequality and the process of national development" Economic Development and Cultural Change,4,3-45.

© 2004-2018 中国地质图书馆版权所有 京ICP备05064691号 京公网安备11010802017129号

地址:北京市海淀区学院路29号 邮编:100083

电话:办公室:(+86 10)66554848;文献借阅、咨询服务、科技查新:66554700