Preference reversals: Time and again
详细信息    查看全文
  • 作者:Carlos Alós-Ferrer ; Ðura-Georg Granić ; Johannes Kern…
  • 关键词:Preference reversals ; Decision times ; Imprecise preferences ; Compatibility hypothesis
  • 刊名:Journal of Risk and Uncertainty
  • 出版年:2016
  • 出版时间:February 2016
  • 年:2016
  • 卷:52
  • 期:1
  • 页码:65-97
  • 全文大小:738 KB
  • 参考文献:Achtziger, A., & Alós-Ferrer, C. (2014). Fast or rational? A response-times study of Bayesian updating. Management Science, 60(4), 923–938.CrossRef
    Alós-Ferrer, C., & Shi, F. (2015). Choice-induced preference change and the free-choice paradigm: a clarification. Judgment and Decision Making, 10(1), 34–49.
    Alós-Ferrer, C., & Strack, F. (2014). From dual processes to multiple selves: implications for economic behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology, 41, 1–11.CrossRef
    Alós-Ferrer, C., Granić, D.G., Shi, F., & Wagner, A.K. (2012). Choices and preferences: evidence from implicit choices and response times. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 48(6), 1336–1342.CrossRef
    Bargh, J.A., & Chartrand, T.L. (2000). The mind in the middle: a practical guide to priming and automaticity research. In Reis, H.T., & Judd, C.M. (Eds.) Handbook of research methods in social and personality psychology (pp. 253–285). NY: Cambridge University Press.
    Bateman, I., Day, B., Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (2007). Can ranking techniques elicit robust values? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 34(1), 49–66.CrossRef
    Becker, G.M., DeGroot, M.H., & Marschak, J. (1964). Measuring utility by a single response sequential method. Behavioral Science, 9(3), 226–232.CrossRef
    Bem, D. (1967). Self-perception: an alternative interpretation of cognitive dissonance phenomena. Psychological Review, 74(3), 183–200.CrossRef
    Blavatskyy, P.R. (2009). Preference reversals and probabilistic decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 39(3), 237–250.CrossRef
    Bleichrodt, H., & Pinto Prades, J.L. (2009). New evidence of preference reversals in health utility measurement. Health Economics, 18(6), 713–726.CrossRef
    Brehm, J.W. (1956). Postdecision changes in the desirability of alternatives. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 52(3), 384–389.CrossRef
    Butler, D.J., & Loomes, G. (2007). Imprecision as an account of the preference reversal phenomenon. The American Economic Review, 97(1), 277–297.CrossRef
    Casey, J.T. (1991). Reversal of the preference reversal phenomenon. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 48(2), 224–251.CrossRef
    Casey, J.T. (1994). Buyers’ pricing behavior for risky alternatives: Encoding processes and preference reversals. Management Science, 40(6), 730–749.CrossRef
    Chabris, C.F., Laibson, D.I., Morris, C.L., Schuldt, J.P., & Taubinsky, D. (2009). The allocation of time in decision-making. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2), 682–637.
    Cubitt, R.P., Munro, A., & Starmer, C. (2004). Testing explanations of preference reversal. The Economic Journal, 114(497), 709–726.CrossRef
    Delquié, P. (1993). Inconsistent trade-offs between attributes: new evidence in preference assessment biases. Management Science, 39(11), 1382–1395.CrossRef
    Evans, JS.B.T. (2008). Dual-processing accounts of reasoning, judgment, and social cognition. Annual Review of Psychology, 59(1), 255–278.CrossRef
    Festinger, L. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
    Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.CrossRef
    Fischer, G.W., Carmon, Z., Ariely, D., & Zauberman, G. (1999). Goal-based construction of preferences: task goals and the prominence effect. Management Science, 45(8), 1057–1075.CrossRef
    Goldstein, W.M., & Einhorn, H.J. (1987). Expression theory and the preference reversal phenomena. Psychological Review, 94(2), 236–254.CrossRef
    Grether, D.M., & Plott, C.R. (1979). Theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon. The American Economic Review, 69(4), 623–638.
    Hershey, J.C., & Schoemaker, P.J.H. (1985). Probability versus certainty equivalence methods in utility measurement: are they equivalent? Management Science, 31(10), 1213–1231.CrossRef
    Hey, J.D. (2001). Does repetition improve consistency? Experimental Economics, 4(1), 5–54.CrossRef
    Jarcho, J.M., Berkman, E.T., & Lieberman, M.D. (2011). The neural basis of rationalization: cognitive dissonance reduction during decision-making. Social Cognitive and Affective Neuroscience, 6(4), 460–467.CrossRef
    Johnson, E.J., & Schkade, D.A. (1989). Bias in utility assessments: further evidence and explanations. Management Science, 35(4), 406–424.CrossRef
    Lindman, H.R. (1971). Inconsistent preferences among gambles. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 89(2), 390–397.CrossRef
    Lindsay, L. (2013). The arguments of utility: preference reversals in expected utility of income models. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 46, 175–189.CrossRef
    Moffatt, P.G. (2005). Stochastic choice and the allocation of cognitive effort. Experimental Economics, 8(4), 369–388.CrossRef
    Oliver, A. (2013). Testing procedural invariance in the context of health. Health Economics, 22(3), 272–288.CrossRef
    Rubinstein, A. (2007). Instinctive and cognitive reasoning: a study of response times. Economic Journal, 117(523), 1243–1259.CrossRef
    Schkade, D.A., & Johnson, E.J. (1989). Cognitive processes in preference reversals. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 44(2), 203–231.CrossRef
    Schmidt, U., & Hey, J.D. (2004). Are preference reversals errors? An experimental investigation. The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 29(3), 207–218.CrossRef
    Schmidt, U., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (2008). Third-generation prospect theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36(3), 203–223.CrossRef
    Seidl, C. (2002). Preference reversal. Journal of Economic Surveys, 16(5), 621–655.CrossRef
    Sharot, T., De-Martino, B., & Dolan, R.J. (2009). How choice reveals and shapes expected hedonic outcome. The Journal of Neuroscience, 29(12), 3760–3765.CrossRef
    Shultz, T.R., Léveillé, E., & Lepper, M.R. (1999). Free choice and cognitive dissonance revisited: choosing “lesser evils” versus “greater goods”. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 25(1), 40–48.CrossRef
    Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1968). Relative importance of probabilities and payoffs in risk taking. Journal of Experimental Psychology Monograph, 78(3, Part 2), 1–18.CrossRef
    Stalmeier, P.F.M., Wakker, P.P., & Bezembinder, T.G.G. (1997). Preference reversals: violations of unidimensional procedure invariance. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 23(4), 1196–1205.
    Strack, F., & Deutsch, R. (2004). Reflective and impulsive determinants of social behavior. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 8(3), 220–247.CrossRef
    Sugden, R. (2003). Reference-dependent subjective expected utility. Journal of Economic Theory, 111, 172–191.CrossRef
    Tversky, A., Sattath, S., & Slovic, P. (1988). Contingent weighting in judgment and choice. Psychological Review, 95(3), 371–384.CrossRef
    Tversky, A., Slovic, P., & Kahneman, D. (1990). The causes of preference reversal. The American Economic Review, 80(1), 204–217.
    Weber, E.U., & Johnson, E.J. (2009). Mindful judgment and decision making. Annual Review of Psychology, 60, 53–85.CrossRef
    Wilcox, N.T. (1993). Lottery choice: incentives, complexity, and decision time. Economic Journal, 103(421), 1397–1417.CrossRef
    Wilcox, N.T. (1994). On a lottery pricing anomaly: time tells the tale. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8(7), 311–324.
  • 作者单位:Carlos Alós-Ferrer (1)
    Ðura-Georg Granić (1) (2)
    Johannes Kern (1)
    Alexander K. Wagner (1) (3)

    1. Department of Economics, University of Cologne, Albertus-Magnus Platz, 50923, Cologne, Germany
    2. Erasmus School of Economics, Erasmus University Rotterdam, P.O. Box 1738, 3000 DR, Rotterdam, Netherlands
    3. Vienna Center for Experimental Economics and Department of Economics, University of Vienna, Oskar-Morgenstern-Platz 1, 1090, Vienna, Austria
  • 刊物类别:Business and Economics
  • 刊物主题:Economics
    Economic Theory
    Microeconomics
    Operation Research and Decision Theory
    Environmental Economics
  • 出版者:Springer Netherlands
  • ISSN:1573-0476
文摘
This paper sheds new light on the preference reversal phenomenon by analyzing decision times in the choice task. In a first experiment, we replicated the standard reversal pattern and found that choices associated with reversals take significantly longer than non-reversals, and non-reversal choices take longer whenever long-shot lotteries are selected. These results can be explained by a combination of noisy lottery evaluations (imprecise preferences) and an overpricing phenomenon associated with the compatibility hypothesis. The first cause explains the existence of reversals, while the second explains the predominance of a particular type thereof. A second experiment showed that the overpricing phenomenon can be shut down, greatly reducing reversals, by using ranking-based, ordinally-framed evaluation tasks. This experiment also disentangled the two determinants of reversals, because imprecise evaluations still deliver testable predictions on decision times even in the absence of the overpricing phenomenon. Strikingly, when unframed ranking tasks were used, decision times in the choice phase were greatly reduced, even though this phase was identical across treatments. This observation is consistent with psychological insights on conflicting decision processes.
NGLC 2004-2010.National Geological Library of China All Rights Reserved.
Add:29 Xueyuan Rd,Haidian District,Beijing,PRC. Mail Add: 8324 mailbox 100083
For exchange or info please contact us via email.